What Local Advocates Won’t Want To See
By Jim Prevor, Editor-in-Chief, Produce Business
Discussions about local sometimes carry a striking resemblance to the child’s tale of The Emperor Who Had No Clothes. Miguel Gómez is a noted academic, coming from a distinguished department, and it is notable that the strongest case he makes is that local has “captured the attention” of everyone. Translation: It is hot and trendy, but there is no research indicating that sales of local are actually any higher than they used to be.
This is significant because it is not clear that the research Professor Gómez and his associates conducted is particularly relevant to the kind of “local” that local advocates are actually advocating. The specific study that Cornell worked on, which dealt with New York State apples, is a case in point: New York had a substantial apple industry long before anyone ever heard of Michael Pollan. In general, when New York State had an apple similar to Washington State, say a Red Delicious, the New York apple brought a higher F.O.B. price than Washington because it was closer to major markets. Put another way, the market adjusted for higher freight costs from Washington by paying New York apple growers more.
Yet we have no sense that local advocates simply want people in Washington to eat Washington apples and people in New York State to eat New York State apples. This would, after all, leave lots of places where they don’t grow many apples without apples. The “locavore” activist wants to create a new paradigm in which growers within regional food systems diversify agriculture and grow multiple items. In fact, they want to avoid monocultures entirely. The ideal model for these advocates is a Community Supported Agriculture or CSA model where the consumer gives a kind of blank check to a farmer who then bases what he grows on what will best sustain the land and the environment rather than consumer demand.
Whatever its flaws, the free market is pretty efficient and, typically, we don’t determine what to buy through a study; we rely on the market to incorporate costs of energy, etc., in the price and then we wind up buying – all things considered – the most efficient product for our needs. Still, Professor Gómez offers four intriguing ideas about which we would say the
following:
1) Indeed, anyone serious about increasing sales and consumption of locally grown and produced foods would be wise to work toward getting such foods into mainstream distribution, which is, by definition, where most of the food is sold. Such advice is, however, almost certain to be ignored by advocates for local for the same reason that advocates for organic are unhappy that Wal-Mart now plays in the game.
Local is not just a matter of geography to its core advocates. It is a proxy for “small scale” for “bio-diverse” for people “knowing who makes their food” and much more. These advocates will be no more happy with Wal-Mart selling more local than they are with it selling more organic. They will feel that one way or another, it cheats the core of what they are looking for.
2) Many local advocates mindlessly assume that “food miles” is, in and of itself, a valuable metric, but fuel use in transport is only slightly more valuable a calculation than food miles – which is almost worthless. First, different regions and different farms grow with different techniques that use different amounts of energy. So grass-fed lamb in New Zealand may overwhelm feed-fed lamb in the UK, regardless of transport. Second, there are many concerns from an output of CO2 to water use that go beyond fuel use. Only a comprehensive lifecycle analysis can even hope to provide a useful piece of data.
Beyond this, whatever resources are used in the production, packaging, and distribution of an item are presumably captured in its price, so it is not clear why we should care about this issue. It seems that the proper role of economists would be to identify externalities that are not properly captured in the price people pay for an item. For example, if a food-processing plant pollutes the air, it may impose costs on society not captured in the price of the product. This is the place where regulations and taxes can have a net positive impact
on society.
3) When regionally produced foods have advantages in flavor or in cost, they have always found a place in the produce distribution system and on the tables of consumers. Still, we have the sense that advocates for local will not find this arrangement acceptable for the precise reason that it depends on neutral parties finding value in selling locally. Advocates want to sell locally precisely when the value is not obvious to those not ideologically committed.
4) In small volumes, selling direct
to consumers can be a highly profitable alternative for the farmer. But for society overall, a closer look at the behavior behind this phenomenon might reveal another perspective: Do farmers who sell at farmers markets pay the proper sales and income taxes? Do cities and towns maximize their revenues or could they rent farmers market land to alternative uses at higher prices?
Externalities can work both sides of this issue, and if our cash-strapped municipalities are giving out for free what they could sell for a high price or if we subsidize the sales force for direct-to-consumer sales with unemployment insurance and disability payments, this might impact the way we view these efforts.
Hats off to Professor Gómez and his associates for trying to bring some hard facts to an area that is driven by ideology. We confess some skepticism as to whether those so driven will actually care about
the facts.